Skip to Content

About: adminturbocargo

Recent Posts by adminturbocargo

Yang Ming to Charter Another 11,000 TEU Newbuild Quartet from Shoei Kisen | Brazil Modal

Image Courtesy: Yang Ming

The signing ceremony was held in Hong Kong on April 10, 2019.

The four boxships have been ordered by Shoei Kisen Kaisha at Imabari yard, according to data provided by Asiasis.

As informed, the vessels are expected to be delivered in the first three quarters of 2022.

Yang Ming’s fleet optimization is part of the company’s strategy aimed at enhancing its mid to long-term operational efficiency and competitiveness.

“In addition to these four new 11,000 TEU containerships, Yang Ming had ordered another ten 11,000 TEU newbuildings through long-term charter agreements with Owners Costamare and Shoei Kisen since 2018, which will enable Yang Ming to have a total of fourteen 11,000 TEU newly-built full containerships during the years 2020 to 2022,” the company said in a statement.

These eco-type new containerships would gradually replace some of Yang Ming’s high-cost, older ships.

Referring to the International Maritime Organization’s (IMO) sulphur cap 2020 which will enter into force on January 1 next year, Yang Ming added:

“Every carrier has prepared accordingly to ensure a smooth transition in operation next year. All the newbuildings Yang Ming has ordered are designed in compliance with the IMO regulation with lower bunker consumption.”

Fonte: http://brazilmodal.com.br/2015/internacional/yang-ming-to-charter-another-11000-teu-newbuild-quartet-from-shoei-kisen/

0 0 Continue Reading →

China's exporters fear heyday is over amid sour mood at Canton Fair as US-China trade war lingers

The optimism expressed by officials from China and the United States suggesting the trade war is almost over has not trickled down to small exporters …

Fonte: https://www.scmp.com/economy/china-economy/article/3006884/chinas-exporters-fear-heyday-over-amid-sour-mood-canton-fair

0 0 Continue Reading →

Siemens enhances HHLA rail network | Brazil Modal

“It is our pleasure to expand the Metrans vehicle fleet by ten multisystem Vectron locomotives from Siemens Mobility. This underlines our ambition to continue growing along the transport streams of the future. The acquisition of additional locomotives will help us to be even more flexible and reliable in responding to the wishes of our customers,” said Peter Kiss, CEO Metrans Group.

“We are confident that the new Vectron locomotives enable our customer Metrans to meet current and future transportation requirements and make its long-term plans successful. The Vectron locomotives are writing a great story since their introduction on the European market and we are proud that, together with Metrans, we can celebrate the 900th Vectron sold,” said Roman Kokšal, CEO Siemens Mobility Czech Republic.

The locomotives for Metrans have a maximum output of 6.4 megawatts and a top speed of 160 km/h, and are equipped with the required national train control systems as well as the European Train Control System (ETCS). The locomotives are certified to operate in Austria, the Czech Republic, Germany, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia. Future upgrades for Bulgaria, Croatia, the Netherlands, Romania, Serbia and Slovenia are possible.

Fonte: http://brazilmodal.com.br/2015/internacional/siemens-enhances-hhla-rail-network/

0 0 Continue Reading →

Happy Easter 2019

pascoa-TURBO

0 0 Continue Reading →

(FTZ) 167

ForeignTrade Zone (FTZ) 167 – Green Bay, Wisconsin;. Notification of Proposed Production Activity. ProAmpac Holdings, Inc. (Flexible Packaging …

Fonte: https://s3.amazonaws.com/public-inspection.federalregister.gov/2019-07802.pdf

0 0 Continue Reading →

Diana Shipping Fixes Capezies with Cargill | Brazil Modal

Illustration. Image Courtesy: Pxhere under CC0 Creative Commons license

Under the deal, the company’s the 180,960 dwt New Orleans started working for Cargill on April 10 at a gross charter rate of USD 15,000 per day.

The charter for the 2015-built bulker was agreed for a period of about sixteen to nineteen months.

Diana Shipping expects the employment to generate around USD 6.98 million of gross revenue for the minimum scheduled period of the time charter.

New Orleans was previously chartered to SwissMarine Services from March 2018 at a gross charter rate of USD 21,000 per day.

Fonte: http://brazilmodal.com.br/2015/internacional/diana-shipping-fixes-capezies-with-cargill/

0 0 Continue Reading →

China’s foreign exchange reserves to maintain upward trend: analysts

Photo: IC

China’s foreign exchange reserves are expected to maintain an upward trend in the coming months as yuan-denominated assets remain more attractive to foreign investors amid renewed optimism for a resolution to the China-US trade war and the country’s continuing opening-up efforts in the financial sector, according to analysts.

China’s foreign exchange reserves rose for a fifth straight month in March, increasing by $9 billion to $3.099 trillion, up 0.3 percent from February, data from the State Administration of Foreign Exchange showed on April 7.

With the economy expected to maintain reasonable growth and improved flexibility in the yuan exchange rate, China’s forex reserves will remain stable, the forex regulator said.

China’s foreign exchange reserves will keep edging up as more foreign capital will be attracted to China’s stock and bond markets, Liu Jian, a senior research fellow at the financial research center under Bank of Communications, told the Global Times on Monday.

Assuming continued US dollar weakness and progress in the trade talks, the yuan is likely to hold on to its recent gains, Liu said.

China’s foreign exchange reserves are mainly composed of the total foreign trade surplus in the current account and the net inflow of foreign direct investment in the capital account.

Dong Dengxin, director of the Finance and Securities Institute at the Wuhan University of Science and Technology, told the Global Times on Monday that as China is promoting opening-up in the financial sector and increasing imports, closer regulation should be put on capital flows.

Increasing foreign exchange reserves will offer more leverage for the country to maintain exchange rate stability, Dong said.

Fonte: http://www.globaltimes.cn/content/1146044.shtml

0 0 Continue Reading →

Satisfaction survey in container transport | Brazil Modal

249 shippers and forwarders who took part in the survey rated the service of container shipping lines with a score of 3.1 on average (which is 0.1 lower than last year) on a scale of 1 (very dissatisfied) to 5 (very satisfied).

Customer satisfaction was reported least favourable for clarity of prices and surchargestransit times, and reliability of booking/cargo shipped as booked scoring between 2.8 and 3.

All the service features were overall awarded mid-range scores; only 4% of customers were “very dissatisfied” with carrier services and only 6% were “very satisfied”.

 

Source: ESC

Fonte: http://brazilmodal.com.br/2015/internacional/satisfaction-survey-in-container-transport/

0 0 Continue Reading →

The Dangers of Trade Orthodoxy – Foreign Policy

From the orthodox view of trade, all nations win as markets spread tranquilly across borders. In reality, trade can often produce just the opposite: fierce market competition and worsening income inequality. Touted as a great employment generator, trade in fact cost a million factory jobs in four industrial U.S. states where angry voters cast ballots for President Donald Trump, according to a study by David Autor of the Massachusetts Institute of Technology and several co-authors. Now his trade war with China threatens to cut off business supply chains and spill into military rivalry.

In the developing world, meanwhile, trade has helped many poorer nations tap into world demand for exports. But there, too, it has caused harm. Even after Mexico’s “lost decade” in the 1980s, only 2 million Mexicans had crossed the U.S. border by 1990 seeking better lives as undocumented residents. But after the 1994 North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), the numbers surged. By 2000, 4.8 million undocumented Mexicans, despairing of their future at home, were in the United States.

Orthodox thinking, it seems, has a problem. On its website, the World Trade Organization (WTO) still has emblazoned the original win-win model published by the British economist David Ricardo in 1817. If Britain uses less labor to make a yard of textiles than to make a gallon of wine, and Portugal uses less labor to make the wine than the textiles, Ricardo argued, they can each produce the good they make most efficiently, trade some of it for the other country’s good, and obtain more of both. Protectionist barriers are akin to throwing rocks in one’s own harbor.

The Ricardian model captures important insights, but its benefits are only fully realized if all its assumptions are met. Ricardo point-blank assumed away today’s fear that free trade allows factories to move abroad. Investors, he maintained, were generally “satisfied with a low rate of profits in their own country, rather than seek a more advantageous employment for their wealth in foreign nations,” he wrote, because they feared locating under “a strange government and new laws.”

His model, as well as modern variants of it, also assume that trade is balanced, both nations enjoy full employment, each nation has a single wage (income inequality is literally zero), and trade doesn’t affect the course of industrial development—all wild stretches. Of course, other models have delved into the issues the Ricardian model assumes away, but none has been so enshrined in contemporary thought.

In fact, Ricardo himself cared deeply about two of the issues his model writes off: income inequality and industrial development. The aristocracy was his particular bugbear. The idle rich monopolized agricultural land and drove up the price of wheat, the staple food of the working class, he argued. He fought against laws blocking grain imports in the hopes of reducing food prices, easing pressure on workers, and still leaving industrialists with higher profits. Since profits were nearly all invested (banking was still rudimentary), if they increased, Ricardo argued, they would spur development.

Beyond using it as an example in his model, Ricardo seems to have thought little about Portugal itself, but its unhappy situation also highlights development concerns that his schema can’t deal with. In 1703, the Royal Navy had sailed into Lisbon and forced Portugal to sign a now famous treaty to trade its wine for British textiles. Portugal never exported enough wine to balance this trade (the Brits, it seems, were insufficient lushes). In real life, to finance the textile trade, Portugal forced slaves to dig gold in Brazil and shipped perhaps 50,000 pounds’ worth every week on packet boats to England.

Demand for Britain’s textiles overseas, key to the early industrial revolution, supported its development. Demand for Portuguese gold supported, well, slaves digging gold. And Britain was not shy about passing acts requiring its colonies to buy more of its wares. “A great empire has been established,” Adam Smith complained, “for the sole purpose of raising up a nation of customers who should be obliged to buy from the shops of our different producers.”

U.S. Treasury Secretary Alexander Hamilton, having learned from that empire’s evident success, called for industrial policies—a national bank and infrastructure construction—and tariffs to shield American industry from foreign competition. Presidents George Washington and John Adams implemented some of these policies, the slaveholding Presidents Thomas Jefferson and Andrew Jackson undermined them (what need have slaveholders for industry?), and then ex-business lawyer Abraham Lincoln championed them.

From the Civil War to World War I, as the United States advanced from peripheral nation to global power, it maintained average tariffs of 40 to 50 percent, Ha-joon Chang of Cambridge University documents in Kicking Away the Ladder: Development Strategy in Historical Perspective. The Smoot-Hawley tariffs that were levied during the Depression—the ones economists never tire of lambasting—were only a bump up to the higher end of the range.

Essentially, all of the countries that we now think of as developed used domestic policies to promote industry and trade protection to shield it, Chang concludes. Modern China’s approach to export promotion and trade protection is just a free variation on Hamilton’s policies and Britain’s before them. Chinese government banks, including the four largest banks in the world, lend to support national manufacturing and booming infrastructure investment, often via state-owned firms. China manipulates its currency to make exports cheaper and imports more expensive, demands that government agencies at all levels buy local, and requires foreign investors to share intellectual property—or just outright appropriates it. “Not unlike the United States in the 19th century,” Wall Street financier Steven Rattner has written, gung-ho Chinese growth policies and lax law enforcement have “an unsavory wild West flavor.”

Another issue Ricardo’s model assumes away—trade’s effect on employment—did not concern politicians until workers gained voting strength after World War I. In a 1937 essay, “Beggar-My-Neighbour Remedies For Unemployment,” the Cambridge University economist Joan Robinson presented win-lose models showing how a nation can use protectionism to run a trade surplus, sustain demand for its goods, and create jobs—all while pushing deficits and unemployment onto its trading partners. Modern economists rail against “beggar-thy neighbor” protectionism but rarely acknowledged her point: why a nation might use protectionism to support its economy to begin with.

Robinson’s concerns loomed large for the negotiators from the 44 Allied nations who met in Bretton Woods in 1944 to negotiate the post-World War II economic order. John Maynard Keynes, leader of the British delegation, had solicited Robinson’s ongoing advice in writing his own economic theory. Harry Dexter White, the U.S. leader, hewed to Keynes’ ideas, as did the overwhelming majority of other delegates. But they all understood Ricardo too.

Believing that trade war had contributed to the Depression and fascism in the 1930s, Keynes called for a global framework that would manage tensions, allow nations to trade peacefully, and sustain full employment. But he and his contemporaries at Bretton Woods did not seek to micromanage gazillions of individual trade rules—unlike Trump today, who believes he can use protectionism to decrease the U.S. trade deficit. The fact is that protectionism rarely affects overall trade deficits or surpluses. For example, throughout the post-World War II decades, Latin American nations such as Mexico, Brazil, and Argentina wielded high tariffs, often exceeding 50 percent, as well as setting fixed quotas on some imports—and still often racked up large trade deficits.

How can a nation with high tariffs run trade deficits? Tariffs regulate what is imported rather than how much. Postwar Latin American regimes would allow in industrial goods they couldn’t produce themselves but block consumer imports—a common development strategy. Overall, they still imported as much as they could borrow from abroad to pay for foreign goods. The United States did something similar after Trump’s tax cuts. Americans had more money in their pocket, but U.S. production couldn’t leap to match the demand, so goods poured in from abroad. The trade deficit swelled.

To prevent such outcomes, when the Bretton Woods negotiators set out to support trade but avoid large imbalances, they focused on financial flows across borders—IOUs nations accumulate in exchange for exports when they run trade surpluses or incur when the run trade deficits. The International Monetary Fund would monitor and control these flows.

The IMF would lend to deficit nations, but if they began borrowing too much, the fund would require them to cut government expenditures to reduce demand or otherwise slow imports. On the flip side, if a nation’s surplus began to rise, the IMF would start requiring measures to correct the problem. Before too long, the IMF would authorize deficit nations to completely halt exchange of the surplus nation’s currency, blocking its exports. Had the IMF operated as planned, China would have never had a chance to rack up its recent trade surpluses.

But the IMF faced immediate problems. After World War II, the administration of President Harry Truman—more economically conservative than the administration of President Franklin D. Roosevelt that had negotiated Bretton Woods—did not want to let any international agency interfere with U.S. trade surpluses. It starved the IMF of capital, personnel, and authority, quashing it for a decade. When the fund finally stirred back to life in the mid-1950s, it set about imposing harsh conditions on deficit nations in exchange for bridge loans. It hardly touched surplus nations.

By the 1960s, as some U.S. sectors went into trade deficit, IMF managing director Pierre-Paul Schweitzer, U.S. representatives to a fund meeting in 1967 in Rio de Janeiro, and other officials pushed to revive something like the original Bretton Woods system. But France, believing it would abet U.S. “hegemony,” opposed the idea, and Japan and Germany, having emerged as major surplus nations, dragged their feet.

Germany now learned to measure economic success not by “domestic well-being,” the economist Adam Tooze has lamented, but by “the scale of its trade surplus.” Though it escapes notice, Germany often runs surpluses in goods and services larger than China’s. Indeed, the financial IOUs Southern European nations signed over to German banks to cover their trade deficits set up the euro crisis.

All along, politicians never really seemed to believe Ricardo. Even U.S. President Bill Clinton, the consummate globalist, promoted NAFTA by promising that it would “create a million jobs in the first five years”—and well-paid jobs at that. Not only did they not materialize, the Ricardian model does not even promise them, but just assumes full employment from the start.

As the touchstone of trade orthodoxy, a position the pragmatic Ricardo himself would hardly have given it, the Ricardian model itself causes harm. By shoving the very idea of trade tensions under the table, it undermines coherent discussion of how to handle them. At best, the result is endless squabbling about dirty exceptions to an imagined world of perfect markets. At worst, the result is trade war, sometimes spilling into real war.

A contemporary revision of the IMF to handle trade tensions might be technically possible—it would first focus on correcting large currency undervaluations or overvaluations (causing sustained surpluses or deficits)—but nations won’t agree to it any time soon. In its absence, they will keep squabbling over trade at best, erupting in trade wars at worst. Global markets, spreading unregulated across national polities, will let capital apply pressure by seeking out cheaper locations to operate—NAFTA helped Mexico attract investment for a few years but soon saw much of it flee for lower-wage China—threatening an equitable income distribution, and on-and-off undermining full employment.

Fonte: https://foreignpolicy.com/2019/04/13/the-dangers-of-trade-orthodoxy/

0 0 Continue Reading →

APL applies new Low Sulphur Fuel surcharge | Brazil Modal

APL will apply the following Low Sulphur Fuel surcharge (LSF) update with effect from 1 May 2019 until further notice, for the service scope stated below:

Origin: Canada (Via Halifax; Vancouver); Canada (via USA (Oakland; San Pedro; Los Angeles; Long Beach; New York; New Jersey; Norfolk; Philadelphia; Baltimore; Charleston; Savannah; Miami; Houston; New Orleans; Seattle; Tacoma)); USA (via Oakland; San Pedro; Los Angeles; Long Beach; New York; New Jersey; Norfolk; Philadelphia; Baltimore; Charleston; Savannah; Miami; Houston; New Orleans; Seattle; Tacoma); USA (via Alaska (Dutch Harbor; Kodiak; Anchorage))

Destination: Austria; Czech Republic; Hungary; Slovakia; Switzerland, North Europe (Germany; Netherlands; Belgium; France; United Kingdom (except Grangemouth, Teesport, Immingham); Ireland); Spain (Bilbao, Gijon, Vigo); Portugal; Denmark (Via Motor)

EQUIPMENT TYPE CURRENCY 20′ 40′ 40H’ 45′
Dry USD 35 70 70 70
Flat Rack/ Open Top/ Tank USD 35 70
Refrigerated USD 35 70 70

 

Origin: Canada (Via Halifax; Vancouver); Canada (via USA (Oakland; San Pedro; Los Angeles; Long Beach; New York; New Jersey; Norfolk; Philadelphia; Baltimore; Charleston; Savannah; Miami; Houston; New Orleans; Seattle; Tacoma)); USA (via Oakland; San Pedro; Los Angeles; Long Beach; New York; New Jersey; Norfolk; Philadelphia; Baltimore; Charleston; Savannah; Miami; Houston; New Orleans; Seattle; Tacoma); USA (via Alaska (Dutch Harbor; Kodiak; Anchorage))

Destination: Scandinavia (Denmark (Except Via Motor); Sweden; Norway; Finland; Iceland); Poland; Russia (Except Vladivostok, Vostochny, Novorossiysk); Estonia; Latvia; Lithuania; United Kingdom (Grangemouth, Teesport, Immingham)

EQUIPMENT TYPE CURRENCY 20′ 40′ 40H’ 45′
Dry USD 50 100 100 100
Flat Rack/ Open Top/ Tank USD 50 100
Refrigerated USD 50 100 100

 

The LSF will be applicable for the service scope stated above and will also be applied to the Freight All Kind (FAK) Basic Ocean Rates. The associated basic freights are available here. Other Bunker related surcharges, Terminal Handling Charges (Origin and/or Destination), Peak Season Surcharge, Security related Surcharges, and similar charges may also apply and are accessible here. Other charges such as contingency and local charges may also apply. All out ports will be subjected to add-ons.

 

Source: APL

Fonte: http://brazilmodal.com.br/2015/internacional/apl-applies-new-low-sulphur-fuel-surcharge/

0 0 Continue Reading →

 

Recent Comments by adminturbocargo

    No comments by adminturbocargo